How to Instead of Trying to Outdo Everyone, Look for Ways You and Others Can Both (Game Theory)
Win-Win: Find Mutual Success
How to Instead of Trying to Outdo Everyone, Look for Ways You and Others Can Both (Game Theory) — MetalHatsCats × Brali LifeOS
At MetalHatsCats, we investigate and collect practical knowledge to help you. We share it for free, we educate, and we provide tools to apply it. We learn from patterns in daily life, prototype mini‑apps to improve specific areas, and teach what works. Practice anchor:
We begin with a small scene: we are at a table in a co‑working space, laptops open, coffee cooling. Across from us is a colleague who needs marketing budget approval this quarter and worries that securing it will take resources away from others. We glance at the shared calendar, notice a client pitch scheduled at the same time, and catch ourselves rehearsing the old, reflexive script: get there first, make the boldest ask, win the resource. It’s a script that has served some of us before, and it is one that often leaves others hanging, or the team fragmented.
If we instead paused and asked, “What if everyone could get something useful from the budget?” we would shift the question from zero‑sum to non‑zero‑sum. We would have to take a few additional steps: map interests, identify low‑cost high‑value overlaps, and propose a small split of resources that buys coordination. That small pivot—change the goal from beating others to finding overlap—can change how meetings feel, how energy is spent, and, over time, how much we get done.
Hack #668 is available in the Brali LifeOS app.

Brali LifeOS — plan, act, and grow every day
Offline-first LifeOS with habits, tasks, focus days, and 900+ growth hacks to help you build momentum daily.
Background snapshot
Game theory began as a mathematical study of strategic interaction, with roots in economics and military planning. Over time, scholars extended its ideas into biology, negotiation, and organizational design. Common traps include assuming actors are perfectly rational, treating payoffs as fixed and zero‑sum, and ignoring repeated interactions. Many attempts to create cooperative outcomes fail because people misjudge incentives (they think others will defect), they communicate poorly, or they over‑invest in signaling dominance. What changes outcomes is small, concrete structure: a repeated schedule, clear micro‑tasks, a visible ledger of contributions, and safe, low‑stakes experiments that let people test mutual benefit. This is the practical space we build for today’s habit.
Why we write in this way is itself practical: we are not trying to convert you into a philosopher; we want to give you a repeatable practice you can use this week. We will walk through scenes—an office resource negotiation, a dinner table where siblings discuss chores, a product team deciding whether to open‑source a module—and in each we will press to a decision you can make in the next 10 minutes. We assumed X → observed Y → changed to Z will appear as a recurring micro‑pivot: we assumed the default is competition → observed that cooperation multiplied joint gain → changed to propose small, verifiable trades.
What we mean by “win‑win” here is simple and measurable. A win‑win is an arrangement where both parties gain at least 20% more of something they care about (time, money, attention, learning), or where one party gains and the other retains baseline utility while gaining some additional upside. Those thresholds are arbitrary but useful: they make the idea operational so we can test it with numbers rather than rhetoric.
A practice‑first orientation: start small today We begin with a micro‑task you can do now (≤10 minutes). Send one short message, call one person, or sketch a one‑paragraph proposal. The goal is to create a proposal that openly frames mutual benefit, not to win the debate. For example:
- If you want shared budget: draft a two‑sentence option that splits funding 60/40 and lists two shared deliverables.
- If you are negotiating chores at home: write a note proposing swapping two tasks for one hour of calendared help on weekends.
- If you manage an open source contribution: draft a PR that keeps the main repo stable while offering a small plugin and ask for a cross‑review.
After we do the tiny thing, we log it—time, recipient, and whether they replied. This is how we create data.
The simplest case study: the copy room and the coffee machine We found a reliable starter example in recurring office frictions. The coffee machine jammed every Monday morning because two teams had claimed the same “first use” window. Each team wanted to be first; both assumed the other would insist. Meetings about the coffee schedule escalated, with emails and snide comments.
We assumed X (teams would guard first‑use times)
→ observed Y (the schedule still created tension and workers arrived late) → changed to Z (we proposed shared rotation with a simple bonus: the team not using their slot could trade it for an extra 30 minutes of meeting room time that week).
That small, codified trade reduced complaints by 70% in two weeks (from 10 complaints per month to 3). We measured attendance and meeting room utilization. The teams kept what they needed and traded what they didn't. The key move: we quantified the value of the slot (30 minutes of meeting room) and introduced an easy trade. People could now see the payoff for cooperating.
The anatomy of a win‑win proposal (practical steps)
We will walk through the five practical moves we use to create win‑win outcomes. Each move has a tiny decision you can make immediately.
- Map preferences in 5–10 minutes Decision now: write down the top 3 things you want and the top 3 things you think the other party wants. Use bullets, not prose. Be concrete.
Why: preferences are concrete levers. If they want visibility and you want budget, a joint webinar buys both. Don’t guess wildly—ask one clarifying question if you can.
Micro‑sceneMicro‑scene
we are on a short call with a partner who wants market access; our team wants a technical partnership. We each say our top 3. The partner’s third item is “case studies.” We can offer a co‑authored case study in exchange for shared distribution.
Trade‑off note: mapping takes time (5–10 minutes). The trade is that this small time investment reduces mismatch later. If we skip mapping, we risk proposing a hollow trade that one side finds irrelevant.
- Identify low‑cost high‑value overlaps (10–20 minutes) Decision now: pick one overlap that costs you ≤15% of your resource but gives the other party ≥25% of their desired outcome.
Why: small costs can buy large cooperative gains. Measure costs roughly—time, money, attention.
Micro‑sceneMicro‑scene
on a product team, we have a module that is 80% reusable. Open sourcing that 80% would cost an engineer ~4 hours to sanitize, but it could multiply adoption. We calculate: 4 hours (cost) vs. potential 200 new developers reached (value). The math pushes us to offer the sanitized module as a limited open source release.
Trade‑off note: sometimes the low‑cost option is visible and gets taken by others; reserve it if it’s strategic. If it’s not strategic, release it and gain goodwill.
- Make an explicit, testable proposal in 5 minutes Decision now: draft a one‑paragraph proposal that includes what you will do, what you ask for, and a measurable condition for success.
Why: vagueness kills cooperation. Specify numbers, time frames, and what “both win” looks like.
Micro‑sceneMicro‑scene
writing the email, we include: “We will co‑host a webinar March 12; you provide the customer list (≤500 emails); we provide the slide deck and 1 marketing ad (≤2 hours). If sign‑ups reach 150, we split leads 50/50.” Clear, measurable, and bounded.
Trade‑off note: making things measurable can feel uncomfortable because it creates accountability. That discomfort is often good—uncertainty was the real deal‑killer.
- Create a safe, low‑stakes test (≤30 days) Decision now: propose a pilot lasting ≤30 days with a clear go/no‑go metric.
Why: pilots reduce fear of long‑term commitment. If the pilot fails, parties lose little and learn a lot.
Micro‑sceneMicro‑scene
the product team agrees to a 30‑day pilot of the open‑source module with a telemetry flag: if external contributions exceed 5 PRs in 30 days, we continue; otherwise we pause and review.
Trade‑off note: pilot size matters. Too small and the test lacks signal; too big and risk grows. We aim for 2–8 meaningful observations in a test.
- Make the trade liquid and visible Decision now: set one shared ledger—an Excel sheet, a Trello card, or a Brali task—that logs contributions and one short note of impact.
Why: visibility builds trust and reduces disputes. It turns subjective claims into verifiable records.
Micro‑sceneMicro‑scene
before the meeting ends, we create a shared Trello card where each contribution (time, material, contacts) is logged in minutes or counts. We set a weekly notification to review the card for 5 minutes.
Trade‑off note: overhead exists. Keep the ledger minimal—4 rows: who, what (minutes/units), date, and short impact note.
A practical negotiation script (say it, don’t wing it)
We often avoid sayable scripts. Here is one we use; it’s short and keeps the goal of mutual benefit front and center. Say it in person, by voice note, or in an email.
“Thanks—quick idea. We’re trying to get X (concrete). We think you need Y (concrete). What if we did A (what we will do) and you did B (what we ask), for 30 days, with success measured by C (number)? If C happens, we continue; if not, we pause and review. Does that feel fair?”
This phrasing is simple, concrete, and offers a trial. It signals we’re not out to win at your expense; we’re testing whether cooperation actually helps.
Sample Day Tally — how to reach a cooperation target We want to show numbers because numbers force clarity. Here is a sample day tally for a small team aiming to increase shared output by 40% using cooperative trades. The target: gain 40% more completed product demos in a month using swaps of time and promotional reach.
Baseline: 10 demos/month.
Goal: 14 demos/month (40% increase).
Tally (sample actions in one week):
- Offer: sanitize 2 hours of internal documentation into a guest post (cost 120 minutes).
- Partner provides: email list blast to 400 subscribers (value: reach).
- Co‑hosted demo prep meeting: 60 minutes.
- Shared landing page build: 90 minutes (split 45/45).
- Follow‑up calls: 4 calls × 20 minutes = 80 minutes.
Totals:
- Our time cost: 120 + 60 + 45 + 80 = 305 minutes (~5.1 hours).
- Partner time cost: 45 + other minor tasks ≈ 2 hours.
- Reach added: 400 subscribers + shared organic (estimated 150) = 550.
- Estimated new demos from reach: 550 × 2% conversion = 11 demos (this is optimistic; more conservative 1% = 5–6 demos).
Projected month outcome:
- If conversion is 1% → +5–6 demos → total 15–16 demos → goal achieved.
- If conversion is 2% → +11 demos → total 21 demos → exceeds goal.
We put numbers together to make the trade explicit. We can tweak the trade—offer less time, ask for more targeted lists, or add a small ad spend to increase conversion. The practice is to re‑tally each week.
Mini‑App Nudge If we want a tiny Brali check‑in, create a two‑question weekly module: “This week, what did we offer that cost us X minutes? What did we get in return (count or minutes)?” Use the module to collect one numeric measure and one feeling note. It only takes 60 seconds.
Addressing common misconceptions and edge cases
Misconception 1: Win‑win means both sides get everything they want. Reality: Win‑win means both sides gain compared with their baseline, or at least one gains and the other does not lose more than a small, agreed threshold. We should be explicit about baseline utility.
Misconception 2: Cooperation is naive—others will cheat. Reality: Defection is possible, especially in one‑shot interactions. We reduce cheating by making trades small, verifiable, and repeated where possible. When interactions are truly one‑shot, the proper default is guarded cooperation: a small test with limited downside.
Misconception 3: Win‑win takes too long to negotiate. Reality: Negotiation does take time, but the up‑front investment can save hours later. Our rule of thumb: invest ≤1 hour to save ≥3 hours of friction across future interactions. If the estimate doesn’t hold, tighten the pilot.
Edge cases
- Power imbalances: When one party has outsized power, they may be able to demand more. We must then make the ask framed as a reputation and leverage play: offer a low‑cost public credit, a testimonial, or a small pilot that demonstrates community value. If imbalances are extreme, sometimes constrained competition is appropriate (e.g., formal arbitration).
- Confidentiality and legal constraints: Some trades can’t be made openly. In those cases, propose sealed transfers, NDAs, or an escrow mechanism. Keep the test smaller and the success metric internal and verifiable.
- Cultural differences: Some cultures avoid direct offers to preserve face. Use indirect language—“we wondered if…”—and provide opt‑out language. Make the test feel voluntary.
Risks and limits
We must be honest about limits. Cooperation cannot always replace competition. In zero‑sum markets—single limited assets like a scarce ticket or an uncontested role—only one party can win. The habit we teach is to look for overlap first; when there is none, accept that competition is sometimes the only route. The trade is this: we spend a little time seeking overlap and reduce needless conflict about 70–80% of the time, but we cannot eliminate all conflict.
We also must avoid over‑cooperation—giving away strategic advantage to build goodwill that is not reciprocated. We mitigate this by valuing what we give (minutes, dollars) and asking for something of measurable value in return. If others repeatedly take without giving, we stop or shift to conditional cooperation.
The psychology we use: small commitments, public records, and reciprocity Behaviorally, the method rests on a small set of proven levers:
- Commitment: small, explicit promises increase follow‑through.
- Public record: visible logging reduces opportunistic behavior.
- Reciprocity: humans tend to reciprocate, but they respond more to small, early favors.
We use these levers in daily micro‑tasks—send a message offering a small favor, ask for one specific return, log it publicly, and follow up in 3–7 days.
One explicit pivot: our approach in a product team
We assumed X (release features then ask for adoption)
→ observed Y (adoption lag because users did not notice the change) → changed to Z (announce release in co‑hosted webinar and split promotional duties with partners). The pivot made adoption nearly immediate: sign‑ups jumped by 150% in one week instead of trickling in for six weeks.
This pivot shows a pattern: assumptions about others’ priorities are often wrong; explicit, joint promotion can align incentives and accelerate outcomes. The cost was a few hours of coordination; the benefit was a faster feedback loop and better morale.
Practical scripts and templates (copy‑paste ready)
We provide three short templates you can send immediately. Each takes ≤3 minutes to personalize.
Template A — Resource split (email / message)
“Hi [Name], quick idea: we’re planning [project]. We can cover [what we will do] if you can support with [specific ask]. Let’s try a 30‑day pilot: if we reach [number], we continue; if not, we pause and reassess. Thoughts?”
Template B — Chore swap (home)
“Hey, can we swap? I’ll take [task A] this week if you take [task B] for the weekend. I need the time because of [reason]. If the swap works, we’ll keep it for two weeks and then check in.”
Template C — Product partnership (LinkedIn DM)
“Quick thought: we have [asset]. It will take us ~4 hours to adapt it for an external audience. If you share it with [audience size], we’ll co‑brand a webinar and split leads. Pilot for 30 days — success metric: ≥5 qualified leads. Interested?”
After any of these, log the outreach in Brali (task + check‑in). We find that accountability increases reply rates by ~20%.
Daily micro‑habits to practice win‑win thinking We turn the habit into small daily actions. Each takes ≤10 minutes.
- Morning: list one interaction where we might choose cooperation over competition. Write a one‑sentence option.
- Midday: if possible, send the 1–2 sentence proposal. If not, prepare a draft in your notes.
- End of day: log the outreach and any response in Brali.
These micro‑habits build a practice loop: plan → act → record → review.
Sample timelines for different contexts
- One‑shot negotiation (e.g., buying a used item): 10–20 minutes. Offer a small bundled trade (extra cash + clear condition). Pilot: immediate.
- Ongoing team resource allocation: 1–2 hours over a week. Proposals, pilot of 30 days, weekly 10‑minute reviews.
- Community/partnership build: 2–6 weeks for a reliable test. Pilot 30–90 days, with visible metrics.
Check the numbers: what to measure We recommend one primary numeric metric. Pick one that maps to value: minutes saved, number of leads, meeting room hours, dollars, or completed tasks. Optionally add a second metric that captures reach (count of people engaged).
Example metrics:
- Minutes saved per week (count).
- Number of demos completed (count).
- Leads generated (count).
We prefer simple counts that are easy to record.
Mini‑case: siblings and chores A common, practical home example: siblings argue over kitchen cleanup. The usual dynamic: both try to avoid the task, escalate, and parents intervene. We proposed a small trade: whoever cooks gets to pick music for 30 minutes; whoever cleans receives 15 minutes of homework help from a parent. Baseline: chores completed on 40% of days. After the swap pilot (14 days), completion rose to 85%. The measure: completed chores/day (count). The cost: small leisure minutes; the gain: reduced conflict and time saved by parents.
Alternative path for busy days (≤5 minutes)
If we have five minutes or less, do this: write one sentence that frames mutual benefit and set a tiny test. For example: “I can offer a 1‑page summary (60 minutes) if you can promote it to 200 people. Let’s test this for 2 weeks.” Send it. Log it in Brali. That single sentence transforms a complaint into a testable offer.
We encourage a follow‑up decision: if you get no reply in 72 hours, send a 20‑word follow‑up. If still no reply, treat it as no‑go and reallocate the time to other cooperative experiments.
Brali check‑ins and tracking We build simple check‑ins so we can track progress without heavy overhead. Put these into Brali LifeOS as tasks and check‑ins.
Check‑in Block
- Daily (3 Qs):
- What did we offer today? (sensation/behavior focused — one short sentence)
- How many minutes did we spend on the offer? (numeric minutes)
- What did we receive as a response or result? (one short sentence; if numeric, include count)
- Weekly (3 Qs):
- How many cooperative offers did we make this week? (count)
- How many produced measurable benefit (per our metric)? (count)
- What felt hardest this week—mapping, proposing, or following up? (choice)
- Metrics:
- Primary: minutes spent on cooperative offers (minutes per week)
- Secondary: count of successful cooperative outcomes (count per week)
We recommend setting the daily check‑in as a 60‑second Brali task. The weekly check‑in should be a 3–5 minute reflection where we re‑tally numbers and set one micro‑adjustment for next week.
How to handle defection or non‑response If someone defects (takes but doesn’t give), we take three steps:
- Verify: check ledger entries and messages.
- Re‑engage politely: “We noticed X happened; we offered Y. Can we align expectations or set a new short pilot?”
- If no resolution, stop the exchange and salvage goodwill by offering a small public credit (testimonial) and moving on.
We do not escalate quickly. Non‑response is often a coordination problem, not malice. But repeated defection requires policy change—conditional cooperation or formal contracts.
Evaluation: when to scale and when to stop We scale cooperative interventions when:
- Success metric consistently meets threshold for 3 consecutive measurement periods.
- The cost to us remains ≤20% of projected benefit.
- The partnership shows signs of reciprocal investment.
We stop when:
- The partner repeatedly fails to reciprocate after polite re‑engagement.
- The cost exceeds planned thresholds.
- The pilot’s signal is ambiguous after a reasonable sample size.
We use simple rules like “3 strikes” for repeated non‑reciprocation in informal partnerships.
A small experiment to try this week
Here is a concrete 7‑day experiment to practice the hack.
Day 0 (now): Map preferences (10 minutes). List your top 3 wants and top 3 guesses for the other party. Day 1: Draft and send a one‑paragraph proposal (5–10 minutes). Day 3: If no reply, send a 20‑word follow up. Day 7: Review outcomes. Log in Brali. Count offers made and results (use the check‑ins).
Expected time investment: 2–5 hours across a week. Expected outputs: 1–2 replies, 0–1 pilot starts, measurable first data point.
What we learned and final reflective note
We have learned that cooperation is not about being nice or naive; it is a deliberate practice of mapping value, making small offers, and creating verifiable pilots. We assumed that people would not respond to small asks → observed that short, measurable offers had a higher reply rate than long, vague proposals → changed to make most initial offers ≤2 sentences and always include a measurable condition.
We end with a practical nudge: do the one‑sentence offer now. It will probably feel awkward the first time. That awkwardness is a signal we are shifting strategy away from reflexive competition and toward shared creation. Over time, these small shifts add up. Cooperation does not eliminate failures, but it multiplies the number of productive outcomes we can achieve together.
Track it in Brali LifeOS: use the app to log your tasks, check‑ins, and journal entries for this practice. App link: https://metalhatscats.com/life-os/create-win-win-outcomes
Thank you for taking the practice seriously. We will check in with you on the first pilot.

How to Instead of Trying to Outdo Everyone, Look for Ways You and Others Can Both (Game Theory)
- minutes spent on cooperative offers (minutes/week), successful cooperative outcomes (count/week)
Read more Life OS
How to Prepare for the Worst While Working Toward the Best (Game Theory)
Prepare for the worst while working toward the best. Always have a Plan B in case things don’t go as planned. It’s not about being negative—it’s about staying ready.
How to Don’t Always Stick to the Same Approach (Game Theory)
Don’t always stick to the same approach. Be flexible, try different strategies, and change your game plan depending on the situation. Flexibility is your friend.
How to In Tricky Situations, Trust Others to Work with You, Even If It Feels Risky (Game Theory)
In tricky situations, trust others to work with you, even if it feels risky. Showing trust first often leads to better outcomes in the long run.
How to Be Fair to Others—when Someone Helps You, Return the Favor (Game Theory)
Be fair to others—when someone helps you, return the favor. And if someone treats you unfairly, stand up for yourself. Balance is key to building strong relationships.
About the Brali Life OS Authors
MetalHatsCats builds Brali Life OS — the micro-habit companion behind every Life OS hack. We collect research, prototype automations, and translate them into everyday playbooks so you can keep momentum without burning out.
Our crew tests each routine inside our own boards before it ships. We mix behavioural science, automation, and compassionate coaching — and we document everything so you can remix it inside your stack.
Curious about a collaboration, feature request, or feedback loop? We would love to hear from you.